Note: I edited this post on 19 February 2014 to replace Chart 5 with the correct chart (mistakenly, the original was for the yet to be completed Parliament 44).
A little over a year ago I wrote a post about how tax-transfer system changes made by Parliament 43 had affected 9 different household types. At the time Parliament 43 was still a going concern, making the picture I painted incomplete. We are now well into Parliament 44 so it’s possible to redo the Parliament 43 post with results for the entire period. I’ve also been giving some attention to 5 additional household types since the original post, so this one will cover 14 in total.
A little over a year ago I wrote a post about how tax-transfer system changes made by Parliament 43 had affected 9 different household types. At the time Parliament 43 was still a going concern, making the picture I painted incomplete. We are now well into Parliament 44 so it’s possible to redo the Parliament 43 post with results for the entire period. I’ve also been giving some attention to 5 additional household types since the original post, so this one will cover 14 in total.
As with the earlier post, the “analysis” (I
hesitate to use such a grand term for this little exercise) essentially
compares the disposable income (ie, after the effect of tax and transfer
payment adjustments) of a particular household type at the election date for
Parliament 43 with the same type of household at the election date for
Parliament 44. This is done for all
private incomes up to $200,000. The
tax-transfer changes that led to any differences between the outcomes on the
two dates are shown graphically.
Importantly, the private income is the same
in real terms at the start and end of the period. That’s because the focus of the post (and
this entire blog really) is changes made by the tax-transfer system alone. Changes to household income brought about by
other factors (eg, wages growth; rises/falls in interest rates) are not
included.
Before digging into the details of the
changes for each household type I’ve put the headline changes together to make
comparisons easier. However, given there
are 14 households I’ve spread this out over 3 line charts to reduce the
clutter. They are roughly grouped as
single person households, couple households and households with children.
Single person households
Chart 1 shows the result for 4 households:
·
Single person aged 25 with
Newstart allowance where relevant (NSA 25)
·
Single person aged 67 with age
pension where relevant (AP 67)
·
Single person aged 25,
full-time tertiary student with a HELP debt and Austudy payment where relevant
(Aus 25)
·
Single person aged 55 with
Newstart allowance where relevant (NSA 55)
In all cases the person does not have
private health insurance. This is so
that changes to the arrangements for the medicare levy surcharge can be shown.
Chart 1
The standout item here is the relatively
large increase in the disposable income of the student, particularly those with
private incomes in the (roughly) $10,000 to $30,000 range. As we’ll see when we get to the individual household
charts, this reflects the introduction of the student startup scholarship and
the relaxation of the Austudy payment income test.
The main theme though is that the
tax-transfer system delivered real gains in disposable income for zero or low
private income households, but actual losses at middle to high incomes. This is a significant change from the pattern
of the preceding 3 Parliaments, all of which did more or less the
opposite. (There are several posts on
this blog that compare outcomes for a particular household type across 4 Parliaments
should you wish to check this out – this one is as good as any, albeit rather incomplete in
relation to Parliament 43.)
Couple households
This broad theme (dare I say
“redistributive”) is also evident when looking at the couple households in
Chart 2. The households shown are:
·
Single (private) income couple,
both members aged 55, with Newstart allowance where relevant (NSA-NSA 100:0 55)
·
Single (private) income couple,
both full-time tertiary students aged 25 with HELP debts and Austudy payment
where relevant (AusP-AusP 100:0 25)
·
Single (private) income couple,
both aged 25, one partner on Newstart allowance and one (the non-worker) on
disability support pension (NSA-DSP 100:0 25)
·
Two income couple, 50/50 income
split, both members age 25, with Newstart allowance where relevant (NSA-NSA
50:50 25)
As before, the households do not have
private health insurance.
Chart 2
As with Chart 1, the biggest change is for
low income students. Also, while the
broad direction of the change is the same as for singles (gains at low incomes,
reductions as incomes rise), the reductions are more substantial. This reflects a deliberate targeting of
single income couples without dependent children over the period. The mechanism for this will become apparent
later when looking at the makeup of the tax-transfer changes affecting
individual households.
Households with dependent children
For the with-children grouping the
households examined are:
·
Single parent aged 35, 2
children aged 8 & 10, Newstart allowance where relevant (NSA 35 (8, 10))
·
Single parent age 30, 2
children aged 6 & 8, parenting payment where relevant (PP 30 (6, 8))
·
Single parent aged 35, 2 children aged 8 &
10, grandfathered parenting payment in 2010; Newstart in 2013 where relevant
(PPS=>NSA 35 (8,10))
·
Two income couple, 50/50 income
split, both aged 40, 2 children age 14 & 16, Newstart allowance where
relevant (NSA-NSA 50:50 40 (14, 16))
·
Single (private) income couple,
both aged 30, 2 children aged 2 & 4, Newstart allowance and parenting
payment where relevant (NSA-PP 100:0 30 (2, 4))
Chart 3
The overall pattern here is similar to the
first two groups – real increases at low incomes; real reductions at higher
incomes – although there is quite a wide variation in the extent of the
gains. Again, the causes of these
disparities will be canvassed in the individual household discussion.
Now to the individual households, starting
with the singles group and the simplest case, a single person.
Single person group
Chart 4 – Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: single person aged 25 with Newstart allowance where
relevant
This might be considered to be the base
case, given that the Australian income tax system is largely focussed on
individuals. The pattern is consistent
with the general theme outlined above, with gains at low incomes and losses
from a little under $40,000. A possible
surprise is the real gain in Newstart allowance (NSA) over the period. It’s the first since July 2000 and like that
earlier increase is a response to changes elsewhere in the system. Back then it was the introduction of the GST;
in Parliament 43 it was to offset the effects of the introduction of carbon
pricing.
This was achieved via the creation of a new
rate component which has been included in pretty much all payments – the clean
energy supplement. The intention was to
make the supplement more than the expected price impact of the carbon changes
to provide a real gain. Measured against
changes in the CPI, this appears to have succeeded. (If you are interested, an explanation of the
way in which the clean energy supplement was created is here.)
The biggest factor in the gain for zero
private income singles is, however, the income support bonus. I have included this because my calculation
system involves “full-year” entitlements, but it’s worth noting that not
everyone gets the bonus. It’s actually a
lucky-dip entitlement, paid twice a year but only to those on payment (in this
case, NSA) on the “test day”. If you
aren’t on payment on the test day, no bonus.
If you are, even if you’ve only been on payment for a day, then the bonus
is yours.
The bonus was something of a sop, offered
in the face of continuing criticism of the level of Newstart rates. It represents a significant increase in the
assistance package in percentage terms, but is cheaper than an actual rate
increase of the same amount because the lucky dip system means large numbers
don’t ever get it.
The other noticeable gain comes from tax
cuts, and pops up from around $10,000 private income. This too was introduced at the same time as
carbon pricing and was intended to assist low income households. It was achieved by a combination of increasing
the tax-free threshold from $6,000 to $18,200, rejigging the low income tax
offset and some associated changes to the marginal tax rates. The net effect was quarantine tax cuts to
lower income households, something of a first given the way in which tax cuts
in earlier Parliaments had been applied (this post compares the last 4
Parliaments and makes this point more obvious).
At incomes from about $40,000 there were no
real changes affecting income tax and so we see the incursion of so-called
bracket creep. As I’m not incorporating
wage increases, in this case what we are seeing is just the decline in real
value of the various tax thresholds which have the effect of increasing the tax
tax. There is, however, a significant
change to the medicare outcome due to the introduction of higher medicare levy
surcharges for those without private health insurance. The effect of crossing the thresholds for
higher surcharges shows up as a sudden increases in the medicare levy impost.
Given that my focus has been to show the
tax transfer changes during the period, I have assumed no private health
cover. However, for those who did have
private cover there were related changes to the level of private health
insurance rebate – it was reduced as incomes crossed the various surcharge
thresholds. So, whether privately
insured or not, real reductions in disposable income occurred due to changes to
medicare/private health insurance arrangements.
Having said that, there’s still that odd
medicare-related gain showing up in the private income range of roughly $84,000
to $88,000. This is because the
threshold for the imposition of the first level surcharge was increased over
the period by reference to wages growth.
Overall wages grew faster than inflation, pushing the threshold up by an
above-CPI amount.
All these changes affected disposable
income as shown in the chart. If you do
check out the earlier 4 Parliament comparison post you will see that the
outcome in Parliament 43 was really very different to the preceding 3. It was quite a substantial change in
direction and one that I don’t think has been fully acknowledged. Think of it this way – if you imagine that
wages growth and tax-transfer changes were rowers in a boat, for Parliaments 40
to 42 both of them were rowing together.
In Parliament 43, at least for those with incomes above $40,000, it’s as
if the tax-transfer rower decided to face the other way, with the two now
pulling in different directions.
Yes, the wages growth rower was pulling
harder, but the effect on the boat of having this sudden turnaround is noticeable
nonetheless.
But enough with the watery analogies, now
to the older singles.
Chart 5 – Percentage change in disposable income over Parliament 43: single person aged 67, age pension where relevant
(I’m not going to discuss the
changes at incomes from around $75,000 and up.
The outcomes are the same as those for younger singles and have already
been outlined in the discussion for that household type.)
At the zero private income point, single
age pensioners had around a 7% real gain in disposable income. Unlike single NSA discussed earlier, this was
achieved entirely through increases in age pension itself (including the new
clean energy supplement) – pensioners (with one exception) didn’t get the
income support bonus. However, bonus or
not, the net gain was still more than double that of single NSA and reflects
the fact that pension rates are linked to wages growth, not just changes in the
CPI.
An interesting result is the rather
different tax outcome compared to that for single NSA. For many years age pensioners have had a more
generous tax treatment than the ordinary taxpayer, a legacy of Howard era
changes. This takes the form of what is
in effect a higher tax-free threshold, an arrangement that did not
significantly change over Parliament 43.
However, an unchanged threshold when combined with higher (taxable)
pension payments and “bracket creep” has caused the effect shown in the
chart. The effect of this is that single
aged with incomes from around $30,000 upward had no gain, or a real reduction
in incomes flowing out of the tax-transfer changes during Parliament 43.
The only other item of note is the
continued erosion of the seniors supplement (the grey item in the chart). This is partly due to the non-indexation of
its income test threshold, and also due to the increasing overlap between the
age pension and the supplement (you can’t get both, as the supplement is in
effect already built into the age pension rate).
Next up, single students.
Chart 6 – Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: single
student aged 25 with a HELP debt, Austudy payment where relevant
As outlined in my initial comments around
Chart 1, this household – single tertiary students with Austudy – had the
biggest real gains from tax-transfer changes over Parliament 43. There were two main drivers for this. First, the introduction of the student
startup scholarship which is provided to most tertiary students who are
receiving Austudy payment, and second, a substantial relaxation of the Austudy
income test (accounting for the large gains starting at around $8,000).
One area of difference between these
results and those for other payments is the presence of a clean energy
advance. However, this is really a
timing thing. All payments initially had
carbon pricing compensation provided via an advance, which was then integrated
into the income support payment proper via the clean energy supplement. The timing of that changeover depended on
when the effects of carbon pricing would show up in the indexation process for
the particular income support payment.
Austudy’s indexation is very lagged – the price effects of the carbon
changes introduced in July 2012 didn’t get picked up until the January 2014
indexation round and from that date the change from the clean energy advance to
a clean energy supplement took place.
That’s outside the timeframe covered by Parliament 43 and hence
Austudy’s results still incorporate the clean energy advance.
At higher incomes the results for tax and
medicare are the same as for the other singles, with the exception of the
presence of HELP related spikes. Again,
this is a timing issue. The thresholds
for the various HELP repayment rates are indexed based on changes in the CPI in
the previous year. This almost
inevitably means the indexation adjustment being made is not the same as the
CPI change in the actual year of implementation, resulting in spikes (up or
down depending on the direction of the CPI change from one year to the next).
Lucky last in the singles households I’m
looking at is persons aged 55 on NSA.
Chart 7 – Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: single person
aged 55 with Newstart allowance where relevant
This household type is included to
illustrate the effect of changes to the mature aged worker tax offset
(MAWTO). The income support and bonus
arrangements are identical to those shown in Chart 4 (singles aged 25). The standout is the markedly different tax
outcome.
Entitlement to the MAWTO was quarantined to those born before 1 July 1957 – previously it was available to everyone aged 55+. The effect is that 55 year olds at the start of Parliament 43 got a better tax deal than 55 year olds at the end.
Removing tax offsets, like MAWTO, was one of the ways in which Parliament 43 sought to improve government revenue. Another offset given a similar treatment was the dependent spouse tax offset. This is discussed in the next group I’m covering – couples.
Removing tax offsets, like MAWTO, was one of the ways in which Parliament 43 sought to improve government revenue. Another offset given a similar treatment was the dependent spouse tax offset. This is discussed in the next group I’m covering – couples.
Couples group
Chart 8 - Percentage change in disposable income over Parliament 43: single income couple, both aged 55, Newstart allowance where relevant
The standout item in this household type is
the reduction in disposable income caused by the increased tax-take. This comes from three sources. First is the loss of the MAWTO, as per the
discussion in respect of Chart 6. The
second is the loss of the dependent spouse tax offset (DSTO). The presence of a partner is no longer
recognised for income tax purposes in households without children where the
partner was born on or after 1 July 1952.
Part of the reason these reductions cut in
at such low private income levels (this is less than the minimum wage) is the
combined effect of the poor design of the income support bonus as applied to
couples (see here for details) and the erroneous way in which the clean energy
supplement was handled (see here for details).
These produce the notch reduction in the NSA result at around $25,000.
At incomes below this point the real gains
in the Newstart outcomes flow from the changes already discussed – the clean
energy supplement and income support bonuses.
The next household is simply a younger
version of the above, which allows us to see the outcomes without the effect of
the loss of MAWTO.
Chart 9 - Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: single income
couple, both aged 25, Newstart allowance where relevant
As you might expect, this is very similar
to the preceding household, the only real difference being the losses on the
tax side max out at around 7% as opposed to around 8% for the older couple.
One minor item in charts 7 and 8 is the low
income supplement for partner 2 (P2) – the small splash of green at a little
over $40,000 private income. This was a
relatively obscure part of the overall carbon pricing household compensation
package and is only available where compensation is not provided elsewhere in
the tax-transfer system. It appears at
incomes above the income support cutout point (below which the clean energy
supplement is in play) but only runs for a few thousand dollars more private
income before entitlement ceases to exist.
Next up, it’s back to students.
Chart 10 - Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: single income
couple, both tertiary students aged 25 with HELP debts, Austudy payment where
relevant
As with the single student shown earlier,
Parliament 43 provided quite significant gains to this couple type at low
incomes through a combination of scholarships, income support bonuses and a
relaxed income test. However, this
largesse comes crashing down once partner 1 (P1) has sufficient income to exit
Austudy payment. Flaws in the design of
the sequential income test used for these payments, plus issues with the design
of the scholarship, the clean energy supplement and the income support bonus
all conspire to remove the gains in a sudden death fashion.
When the effect of the removal of the DSTO
is added in we see an amazing turnaround from an almost 20% real gain for those
at around $25,000 to an almost 7% loss at around $40,000. In fact, so substantial are these reductions
that students in this situation may find their financial position improves by
working less, something I examined in more detail in this post.
One criticism of the couple households I’ve
chosen to look at (so far) is that they are all single income, and that losses
due to the removal of the DSTO are actually a good thing. Indeed, the removal of that offset was a
deliberate decision, aimed squarely at getting rid of a supposedly out-of-date
notion of dependency and providing a bit of an incentive for second earners to
enter the workforce. No doubt the fact
that there are savings to be had from such a change helped ease the way.
Nonetheless, within the rhetoric around the
change there was recognition that for some couples there may still a case for
providing a tax-offset based on dependency.
There are two main scenarios where this is still seen as appropriate:
·
Where one partner is reasonably
unable to work due to caring commitments;
·
Where one partner is reasonably
unable to work due to invalidity
Given this policy position I’ll look at one
more single income couple type before moving on to a two-income couple. The household type I’ve chosen to reflect
this policy setting is a single income couple where one is an “invalid” (to use
the tax legislation term), eligible for disability support pension (DSP).
Chart 11 - Percentage change in disposable income over Parliament 43: single income couple, both aged 25, one an invalid. Newstart allowance and disability support pension where relevant
This household really shows off the “gains
at low incomes; reductions at higher incomes” trend of Parliament 43, with a
marked change in outcome at around $70,000.
At the zero income point most of the gain
for the household comes from increases in the DSP, which dwarfs the gain for
the NSA partner, even with the NSA income support bonus (there was no bonus for
DSP). This is a result of the different
rate setting (indexation, etc) arrangements for pensions compared to benefits
like NSA. The former is benchmarked to
wages as well as being adjusted for changes in the CPI and
pensioner/beneficiary living cost index (PBLCI), whereas NSA is CPI adjusted
only.
At around $70,000 entitlement to pension
cuts out under the income test, leading to the substantial reduction in
disposable income. The marked change in
the tax result reflects the DSTO rules discussed earlier. The working partner is able to claim the offset
provided the “invalid” partner is receiving DSP. Once DSP entitlement is lost so too is access
to the spouse tax offset, causing an increase in tax payable by the household.
This is one of the perils of “piggybacking”
entitlement to one scheme onto another – in this case relying on receipt of DSP
as the marker of invalidity. The rule in
this case also undoes one of the eligibility criteria for the spouse tax offset
– it’s supposed to be available to households where the “breadwinner” income is
below $150,000. Linking the offset to
DSP receipt has the effect of causing entitlement to be lost at less than half
this amount.
But again, it’s a cheap way of running the
thing.
The final couple household I’ll look at is,
at last, a two income one.
Chart 12 - Percentage change in disposable income over Parliament 43: two income couple (50:50 split), both aged 25. Newstart allowance where relevant.
As a two-income couple, the dependent
spouse tax offset does not feature and as you can’t lose what you don’t have
there’s nothing like the tax losses experienced by the single income couple of
the same age. In fact, although the
tax-transfer changes still follow the pattern of turning negative at higher
incomes, this doesn’t occur until around the $75,000 mark – a sharp contrast to
the $27,000 or so point for single income couples (see Chart 8).
Similarly, the gains on the income support
side are greater from around $22,500 than for the single income couple – more
than double in fact.
And with that comes the end of the
couples. Now to the households with
dependent children.
Dependent children group
Chart 13 - Percentage change in disposable income over Parliament 43: sole parent age 35, two children aged 8 & 10, Newstart allowance where relevant
Single/sole parents were very much in the
news during Parliament 43, largely due to the late-term decision to remove the
special “grandfathering” arrangements that had applied since July 2006. This affected people who had been continuously
in receipt of parenting payment as a single person since before that date. The grandfathering ceased with effect from 1
January 2013.
To cover this group and the “standard”
arrangements that have been in place for non-grandfathered people since July
2006 I’ll be looking at three different sole parent households. The first of these, shown in Chart 12 above,
compares a single person with 2 children under the standard rules at the start
of the period, with a similarly constituted household at the end. In this case the income support payment is
Newstart allowance, as the youngest child is aged 8 or more.
The standout item is the gain in NSA,
peaking at about 12%. This triangular
shape is a result of the change to the NSA income test taper rate for single
“principal carer” parents from the generally applicable 50% & 60% to
40%. This took effect from 1 January
2013, coinciding with the removal of the grandfathering provisions. The idea was presumably to ease the
transition because up to that point the losses experienced by sole parents
moving from parenting payment to NSA were enormous for those already working
(see this post for details).
Relaxing the income test took some of the
sting out of the transition for the ex-grandfathered group, but also
significantly improved the disposable income of the sole parent NSA population
already subject to the “new” July 2006 rules.
In addition to the gain from NSA, the
school bonus also appeared during Parliament 43, further adding to the improved
financial outcomes for this household type.
As with the earlier households, at higher
incomes bracket creep style effects cause an increase in the tax take relative
to 2010, but a similar thing can be seen with family tax benefit Part A and
Part B. Both of these were subject to
indexation freezes on some of their income test parameters, resulting in a fall
in value in real terms.
For single parents whose youngest child is
under 8 years, the usual entitlement is parenting payment (PPS), and that
household is next.
Chart 14 - Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: sole parent age 30, two children aged 6 & 8,
parenting payment where relevant
The not-inconsiderable increase at zero
private income for this group was driven by the introduction of the schoolkids
bonus, the income support bonus (single parenting payment recipients were the
only pensioners to receive it) and the use of wages growth benchmarking to set
the base rate of parenting payment itself.
At higher incomes (ie, from around $65,000)
some additional assistance was provided via the single income family
supplement, another carbon pricing compensation measure, this time targeted at
single income families with children.
However neither it nor the schoolkids bonus was enough to offset the
negative effect of the taxation “bracket creep” combined with the impact of
freezes to some FTB A income test parameters.
The net effect is that the overall picture
follows the now familiar pattern of gains at the low income end and losses at
higher incomes. However, in this case
the losses do not appear until around the $100,000 mark, the cause of which is
largely the schoolkids bonus. That bonus
is slated for removal by the current Government and given its importance in the
results for with-child households so far, this will have a strongly negative
impact on outcomes during Parliament 44.
Now to the “grandfathered” group, that
attracted so much attention during the latter period of Parliament 43.
Chart 15 - Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: sole parent aged 35, 2 children aged 8 & 10,
grandfathered parenting payment in 2010; Newstart in 2013 where relevant
Before turning to the chart itself, just a
reminder about how they work in general.
I’m comparing the disposable income (ie, after tax and transfer payment
effects) of a particular household type in 2010 with the same type
of household in 2013. It’s not comparing
the same household – it would not be possible to say, for example, that children were the same ages at the start and end of the period if I did.
That means the results shown in this chart
are not a depiction of what happened to a particular household when the
grandfathering rules changed. Instead,
I’m showing the difference in the treatment of this particular household type
at the election dates. One clear example
of this is the way the schookids bonus shows up. In the chart it’s a gain – there was no
schoolkids bonus in 2010; there was in 2013.
But on January 1 2013 when the grandfathering rules changed it already
existed and individual households would not have gained (or lost) that payment.
In the chart we can see that the income
support package (parenting payment in 2010 versus Newstart allowance plus the
income support bonus in 2013) has substantially reduced over the period. This comes from a lower rate (as shown at the
zero private income point) plus, as income rises, the effects of a tighter
income test (a lower income threshold before private income reduces payment).
The change from parenting payment (which
for singles is a pension) to Newstart also means the loss of access to the
pensioner tax offset (the 2010 version in this example), which results in a
higher tax liability even though taxable income is less than before. That (and a bit of bracket creep) is the cause
of the triangular red tax part of the chart, under the income support
reduction.
The income support and tax related losses
have been partly offset by the introduction of the schookids bonus, which for
some households outside of the income support system actually led to a real
gain over the period (ie in the broad income range $50,000 to $100,000. At higher incomes the pattern reverts to the
overall loss position evident in the other household charts, in this case with
the addition of the income-test indexation freeze induced decline in the value
of FTB A and FTB B.
That covers the three single parent
household types I’ve done calculations for (there are of course many types, but
these are the main groups) so it’s now time to look at some couples with dependent
children households.
Chart 16 - Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: two income couple (50:50 split), both aged 40, with
2 children (14 & 16). Newstart
allowance where relevant for the adults.
I
picked this household not so much for the 50:50 income split (the discussion
around Chart 11 covers that aspect) but for the changes to youth allowance and
FTB A.
The treatment of full-time secondary
student children aged 16+ underwent quite a change during Parliament 43. At the election date such children could
attract either youth allowance or a low (aka base) rate of FTB A. At low incomes getting youth allowance was
pretty much a no-brainer, but as parental incomes increased there came a point
where it was better to be in the FTB A payment system than remain in youth
allowance.
Deciding which payment stream the child
should be in was fraught with difficulty, particularly where there was more
than one child in the family, one of whom was under 16. The change reflected in the chart above was
to extend the 13-15 year old child rate of FTB A to full-time secondary
students. This meant that when the child
turned 16 at high school or college there was no longer a need to try and work
out the most advantageous payment route.
Additionally, the FTB A rate was also higher than the youth allowance
rate, making it a positive outcome overall for most households.
The chart illustrates a loss of youth
allowance (the negative lilac shade) which is more than offset by increased FTB
A. This improved outcome extended (in
this household type) to incomes a little over $90,000 a year – a widespread
gain. The household also benefited from
the previously discussed schoolkids bonus.
The schoolkids bonus does provide quite a
substantial gain for household types that pick it up but, as the name suggests,
it’s not available to families with children under school age. So the final household type will look at the
change over Parliament 43 for a family with young children.
Chart 17 - Percentage change in disposable
income over Parliament 43: single (private) income couple, both aged 30, 2
children aged 2 & 4, Newstart allowance and parenting payment where
relevant
This chart illustrates (through its
absence) what a difference the schoolkids bonus made. For this household type gains were limited to
those flowing from the clean energy supplement’s incorporation into the income
support and family tax benefit payments, plus the tax cuts mentioned way back
under Chart 4. From an income of a little
under $40,000, the tax-transfer system delivered real losses.
Interestingly, for all the other with-child
households considered, real losses did not arise until private income reached
around $100,000. Again, this is
attributable to the schoolkids bonus.
The current Government has plans to abolish this payment, along with the
income support bonus, during Parliament 44.
Given the significant impact these two payments had in the results shown
in all the households considered here (with the exception of the age pensioner
in Chart 5), their abolition will produce markedly negative outcomes. In light of that, I’m inclined to repeat this
exercise for Parliament 44 as we progress through the term. Stay tuned.
Just wanted to say that this is great (and useful) work.
ReplyDeleteOne thing I have always felt is that it doesn't take much of a change in weekly income to go from feeling stretched financially, and having to scrimp to get by, to feeling quite adequate. In Brisbane I reckon that for a family of 4 going from $900 per week net income, to $1100, makes a massive difference.
Maybe that's a product of high rents - if you are spending 50% of your income on rent utilities etc, and maybe 70% if you include food and cost of running a car, then you are actually getting a 75% increase in 'discretionary' or 'luxury' expenditure.
I also notice that in your charts that at this income level ($50k or so) is where the changes are steepest (noting that this is the change of the 43rd parliament, and not net transfers).
Sometimes I wonder if in the background there are rules of thumb being applied. Families on <$50k need more support, those with $100k don't. Maybe that's a philosophical disposition of labour. Of course, this always has the problem of generating higher effective marginal tax rates.
Anyway, rant over. Food for thought I guess. Top work again.
Thanks! When I was working in the public service on this stuff, one of the constraints was the number of households around the $50K mark. Anything that would give money around that income was hideously expensive. Perhaps unsurprisingly, the largesse from system changes often seems to dip in that region!
ReplyDelete